9829

Liability Insurance Desirability under Lognormal Loss Distributions

Consider an entity facing potential liability that has purchased a liability insurance contract providing that it will pay a third party up to an amount if a judgment is rendered. If the insured could act selfishly, it would prefer an insurance contract that would "diminish": it would specify that in the event a judgment against the insured would, even with the existence of the liability insurance, bankrupt the insured, the insurer should pay nothing. This is so because payments to a third party in such a setting do essentially nothing to help the insured, but drive up the cost of premiums because the insurer must pay. Either as the result of regulation or custom, however, such "diminution" provisions are generally unlawful. This is so because diminution might otherwise prevent victims from being compensated more fully when individuals with liability insurance injure them. This restriction on freedom of contract means, however, that there are some settings in which insureds, even though they might like to transfer risk, find it undesirable to do so.
This Demonstration, a close cousin of The Efficient Dual-Limit Liability Insurance Contract, explores the settings in which "diminution" restricts risk transfer. The model is idealized by considering liability insurance policies that pay the lesser of the amount for which the wrongdoer is liable and a policy limit . It further assumes, for purposes of deriving a closed-form expression capable of rapid evaluation, that is drawn from a mixture distribution in which a fraction of the time is zero (no liability-creating event occurs), and the remaining fraction of the time is drawn from a lognormal distribution with a mean of and a standard deviation equal to . The actual amount paid by the wrongdoer is thus , but censored to lie between 0 and the amount of wealth on which a judgment can be executed. The insured pays a premium multiplied by the mean of , where represents a load. The insured seeks to minimize the sum of its premium and its residual risk, where the latter is computed to be equal to the mean of a distribution , but transformed to subtract the limit of liability and censored to lie between 0 and . differs from in that, in order to simulate risk aversion, the insured treats the mean loss as being not but , where is a level of risk aversion ranging from 0 to .
The Demonstration produces a "region plot" showing for different values of , the insured's assets available for execution, and for , the insured's risk aversion, the situations in which full insurance () is preferable to no insurance (). (Some study indicates that partial insurance is never the best decision for the insured.) You choose the remaining parameters, using the controls. When executing this Demonstration on slower computers, you may wish to set the performance goal to "speed"; otherwise "quality" gives somewhat better results.
Here is what you are likely to observe:
• The frequency with which liability-creating events occur turns out to be irrelevant to the decision whether to purchase full insurance.
• Larger mean losses shrink the wealth-risk aversion combinations for which full insurance is desirable.
• More variable losses (higher standard deviation fraction) shrink the wealth-risk aversion combinations for which full insurance is desirable.
• Higher premium loads shrink the wealth-risk aversion combinations for which full insurance is desirable.
• Holding everything else constant, higher risk aversion decreases (but only up to a point) the minimum level of wealth for which full insurance is desirable.

SNAPSHOTS

  • [Snapshot]
  • [Snapshot]
  • [Snapshot]

DETAILS

The combinations of wealth and risk aversion that result in full insurance shrink when:
Snapshot 1: mean losses are larger
Snapshot 2: the standard deviation of losses is larger
Snapshot 3: the premium load is greater
This Demonstration makes use of the Mathematica compiler to achieve additional speed. It also has used
 Experimental`OptimizeExpression in order to develop efficient primitives in the computation of premium and residual risk.
The method of parameterizing risk aversion used in this Demonstration is somewhat unorthodox, but has the virtue of achieving a closed-form solution. The idea is basically to treat risk aversion as if you were drawing from a distribution shaped similarly to the original distribution but with a higher mean. Here, in computing risk, we draw from a distribution with mean , which collapses to if risk aversion is zero. The idea derives from the concept of spectral measures which, as discussed by the author here, is similar to drawing from an -order distribution of observations of a loss distribution. Such an order distribution generally results in higher draws than the original distribution. Thus, drawing from an order distribution is similar to drawing from a distribution that is shaped similarly but has a higher mean. It is thus a reasonable way of simulating risk aversion.
A lognormal distribution is used here because (a) judgments in lawsuits are sometimes modeled as emerging from lognormal distributions; and (b) it results in a closed-form solution to the problem at hand when used in conjunction with the method described above for risk aversion. The principles shown in this Demonstration are likely to be applicable, however, to a broader class of loss distributions. The key is to be able to scale the wealth of the insured available for execution to some metric of the distribution, such as the upper bound of its domain, or some high quantile of the distribution.
The lognormal distribution employed in the code here has been reparameterized to permit more direct representation of mean and standard deviation.
Although most liability insurance contracts contain a clause prohibiting the insurer from reducing the amount it pays a third party based on their insured's insolvency, some insurance contracts do not. Notably, reinsurance contracts sometimes do not have such a clause nor do some maritime insurance policies.
The expression for the premium is derived from evaluating the following Mathematica expression:
Simplify[(1 + λ) f Mean[CensoredDistribution[{0, L}, LogNormalDistribution2[μ, σ]]]]
The expression for the value of the residual risk is derived from evaluating the following Mathematica expression:
Simplify[f Mean[CensoredDistribution[{0, w}, TransformedDistribution[x - L, Distributed[x, LogNormalDistribution2[μ (1 + ρ), σ]] ]]]]
References
[1] S. Shavell, "The Judgment Proof Problem," International Review of Law and Economics 6, 1986 pp. 45–58.
[2] S. Chandler, "A 'Genetically Modified' Liability Insurance Contract," University of Connecticut Insurance Law Journal, 13(2), 2007 pp. 203–265. insurancejournal.org/wp-content/uploads/2011/07/15.pdf.
    • Share:

Embed Interactive Demonstration New!

Just copy and paste this snippet of JavaScript code into your website or blog to put the live Demonstration on your site. More details »

Files require Wolfram CDF Player or Mathematica.









 
RELATED RESOURCES
Mathematica »
The #1 tool for creating Demonstrations
and anything technical.
Wolfram|Alpha »
Explore anything with the first
computational knowledge engine.
MathWorld »
The web's most extensive
mathematics resource.
Course Assistant Apps »
An app for every course—
right in the palm of your hand.
Wolfram Blog »
Read our views on math,
science, and technology.
Computable Document Format »
The format that makes Demonstrations
(and any information) easy to share and
interact with.
STEM Initiative »
Programs & resources for
educators, schools & students.
Computerbasedmath.org »
Join the initiative for modernizing
math education.
Step-by-step Solutions »
Walk through homework problems one step at a time, with hints to help along the way.
Wolfram Problem Generator »
Unlimited random practice problems and answers with built-in Step-by-step solutions. Practice online or make a printable study sheet.
Wolfram Language »
Knowledge-based programming for everyone.
Powered by Wolfram Mathematica © 2014 Wolfram Demonstrations Project & Contributors  |  Terms of Use  |  Privacy Policy  |  RSS Give us your feedback
Note: To run this Demonstration you need Mathematica 7+ or the free Mathematica Player 7EX
Download or upgrade to Mathematica Player 7EX
I already have Mathematica Player or Mathematica 7+